A Grécia e Portugal: uma crise em dois casos da geopolítica (1)

O título do post, resume o conteúdo. Obcecados alguns dos Estados europeus com as suas astronómicas dívidas, correm sérios rumores que parecem garantir a existência de um chamado Plano B para a sobrevivência do Euro. Num artigo (ver abaixo, na íntegra), The Economist longamente apresenta os dois cenários possíveis, entre os quais uma expulsão em massa satisfaria as necessidades imediatas dos países do chamado núcleo duro da moeda única. Persistindo no erro que tem varrido a Europa na última década, a leitura do artigo apenas nos apresenta aspectos relacionados com a dívida e finanças, pouco falando de economia e totalmente ignorando aquele aspecto fundamental e hoje em dia inatingível pelas cúpulas dirigentes europeias: a política.

Para o que mais nos importa de imediato, apresentemos então dois casos bastante distintos como a Grécia e Portugal. Não nos referindo especificamente às agruras e misérias da dívida, salientamos então os ignorados aspectos políticos que a situação geográfica destes dois Estados implicam.

1. A Grécia.

A situação parece ser insolúvel e de quase certeiro vaticinar de falência do todo. Por mais planos e cabazes de dinheiro vertidos nos cofres de Atenas, o resultado parece ser aquele que todos há muito adivinharam. Os gregos não percebem a austeridade, não a aceitam, nem estão dispostos a deixar para trás os sonhos de telenovela dos últimos vinte e cinco anos. Simplesmente, as condições políticas da Grécia impelem à rejeição de qualquer modelo de austeridade e a Europa deveria ter em conta o conturbado século passado, onde uma guerra civil por quase todos os estrangeiros esquecida ou minimizada, serve ainda como pano de fundo ao confronto das várias famílias políticas daquele país balcânico. Para agravar a situação, a ascensão turca e o incontido desejo do restaurar de uma hegemonia perdida, coloca a Grécia numa posição central na luta pelo domínio regional. Sendo um membro da NATO , o país dos helenos foi ao longo das décadas da Guerra Fria, um dos pilares do controlo ocidental – leia-se norte-americano – do acesso russo ao Mediterrâneo e Médio Oriente, garantindo uma longa hegemonia da Aliança Atlântica e aquele indisfarçável sentimento de cerco de que o poderosamente armado regime soviético de forma inglória se queixava.

 

A situação é hoje muito diferente e os recentes acontecimentos no Norte de África e no Médio Oriente, aconselhariam um repensar da estratégia norte-americana, aparentemente encantada com a fortaleza turca que por mais imaginação que possamos ter, é abertamente detestada por todos os vizinhos. Oa americanos fazem girar o seu pensamento em torno de negócios imediatos relacionados com a especulação e a garantia do acesso à energia e matérias primas. Não se prendem aqueles vizinhos rancores, com os aspectos da mais recente evolução interna da Turquia, mas de facto, tal se deve à própria origem e estabelecimento do Estado turco às portas da Europa. Assim sendo, é uma antiga história que tem 1453 como convencional marco e que depois conheceria outras etapas que trouxeram a bandeira vermelha com o crescente branco até às portas de Viena e às Colunas de Hércules. Em suma, quinhentos anos deixaram profundas recordações de humilhações, prepotência e rivalidades que bastas vezes se traduziram em conflitos militares.

Bem ao contrário dos pré-púberes imediatistas políticos dos nossos dias, vinte gerações pesam sobre uma importantíssima região do planeta e os EUA poderiam esforçar-se por não ignorarem com a contumácia displicência, certezas enraizadas e antigos preconceitos ciclicamente revisitados. A verdade é que desaparecido o mundo bipolar, a poderosa América acabou por ter sido a patrocinadora deste outro em que ainda vivemos, onde a China e a Rússia parecem regressar à estilhaçada amizade dos anos 50, afectuosamente enlaçantes dos dois grandes países do comunismo de Estaline e Mao. Vizinhos que partilham uma fronteira longuíssima e potencializadorade uma catástrofe militar, chineses e russos confluem em aspectos essenciais que se radicam, sobretudo, na luta pelo enfraquecimento da potência americana e em sentido lato, ocidental. É esta na sua essência, a válvula de escape encontrada. A Rússia sente-se europeia, se a Europa se tornar em definitivo, num espaço não hostil e acomodado à hegemonia – julgada pelos russos como natural – da grande potência continental, reconhecendo-se assim de forma implícita, as esquecidas teorias de Haushofer. Restar-nos-á saber se na Alemanha ainda persistem vestígios do pressuposto da massa continental euro-asiática que controlaria o mundo. Se assim for, o Plano B consistirá no primeiro passo para o fim daquela Alemanha que há perto de setenta anos enveredou pelo atlantismo. A possibilidade parece absurda, dado o facto de a Rússia dos nossos dias, ser um Estado muito diferente daquele que há uns cem anos era formado por uma massa de camponeses submetidos e por uns tantos centros urbanos onde brilhavam as luzes da cultura ocidental. Conhecidos os cada vez mais pitorescos aspectos da permeabilidade da economia, finança e da segurança americana, a questão europeia, cada vez mais abstrusa e passível de rápido controlo através do estrangulamento propiciado pelas dificuldades do acesso à energia, decerto surgirá  como objecto a utilizar para a obtenção de certos fins. Criar todas as condições para a colocação em prática do Plano B de exclusão da Grécia e dos outros quatro Estados em dificuldades, significará a irreversível satelização do para já resgatado núcleo duro do Euro. Notemos que a Europa não existe como potência militar e muito menos ainda, como entidade política coerente. Não existe nem poderá existir como tal, entendendo-se aquele essencial sentido de unidade que os sempre chamados “precursores norte-americanos,” apresentam como exemplo histórico.

 

A exclusão da Grécia do espaço Euro, inevitavelmente trará gravosas consequências políticas, entre as quais avulta o seu posicionamento na relação de forças daquilo a que outrora chamávamos de blocos político-militares. Sem sequer ter verdadeiramente encetado aquele caminho de reformas e cortes a que os portugueses já se habituaram, os gregos poderão impor a uma classe política condicionada pela rua, opções que alterarão o mapa geoestratégico daquela região. O sólido estabelecimento russo – e chinês – nos portos helénicos, o afluir de caudais financeiros provenientes das mesmas paragens e a satisfação de necessidades imediatas da Grécia, não poderão ser evitados após o ultrapassar daquela linha divisória que a pertença ou não ao Euro significa.  Há poucos anos, a intervenção americana no Iraque reacendeu os apetites turcos quanto às regiões do norte daquele estraçalhado arremedo de país e isto não apenas devido à cobiça pelos recursos económicos propiciados por aquela província – Mossul e área circundante -, mas também, pela enésima tentativa de resolução forçada do problema curdo e das rivalidades com a Síria e o Irão. Uma Turquia demasiadamente próxima de Washington, implica o simétrico afastamento de Atenas e uma rápida procura de novas alianças que conjurem a ameaça, principalmente quando esta agora se reveste de argumentos religiosos persistentemente prosseguidos pelo poder instalado em Ancara. Durante demasiado tempo, os europeus continuaram a encarar a Turquia sob o prisma da velha Cosntantinopla dos sultões e dos dourados da herança do Império Romano do Oriente. Nada de mais errado, pois o conceito que os próprios turcos fazem do seu país e nação, é infinitamente mais lato que aquele apresentado nos mapas que delimitam fronteiras e esperadas influências. O relacionamento com Israel, até há pouco apresentado como exemplar, fatalmente deteriora-se, devendo-se este ocaso, às implicações da progressiva aproximação do Estado turco aos fundamentos religiosos que um dia lhe garantiram a hegemonia no Islão. Até nisso os norte-americanos se equivocam na escolha aparentemente já decidida, garantindo de antemão, um  crescendo da conflituosidade entre turcos e israelitas. Como optará então a administração americana?  Há quem suspeite do entusiasmo dos EUA por uma adesão turca à U.E., como primeiro argumento e trampolim para um outro alargamento a Israel. Uma loucura que definitivamente arruinaria um projecto europeu que há uns vinte anos, para efeitos práticos deixou de o ser.

 

Regressando à situação grega, o aspecto essencial consiste na total desarticulação existente do outrora relativamente sólido espaço euro-atlântico que hoje parece definitivamente abalado. A fuga da Grécia ao temperado controlo europeu, significará também um rápido afastamento em relação às alianças tradicionais e os russos poderão mesmo apresentar como recurso mobilizador de novas boas vontades, a ortodoxia  que um dia mobilizou os Balcãs orientais na luta contra a Sublime Porta. Se isso simultaneamente significar a quebra do sonho de uma Europa onde todos se “pareçam ricos como os alemães”, tal não parecerá pecha ou irreparável desastre, pois a actual situação já colocou os gregos perante realidades que há muito teimavam em ignorar. Novas formas de desenvolvimento – neste caso podíamos dizer adaptação – da economia, também trarão outras novidades no campo da organização política, onde poderá despontar uma democracia à russa.

 

Não estamos no plano das suposições, mas em Berlim, Paris e Bruxelas, a razão parece não prevalecer sobre a mensagem eleitoral a difundir pelos próximos noticiários.

 

(continua)

ANGELA MERKEL, the German chancellor—and also, in effect, the euro area’s boss—has always insisted that she wants to preserve the euro area in its current form. But as the euro crisis intensifies and the potential bills for Germany mount, she would be imprudent not to be considering a Plan B. Drafted in utmost secrecy by a few trusted officials for the chancellor’s eyes only, this is what the memorandum outlining a contingency plan might say.

TO: Angela Merkel
FROM: ???
SUBJECT: Plan B

Related topics

THE CURRENT IMPASSE

I. Since the euro crisis started over two years ago you have said that Germany will defend the single currency, based on your conviction, shared by business and the political class, that its survival is in our national interest. To that end Germany has pledged large amounts of public money, both in our contributions to various rescue funds and through the Bundesbank’s share of risks taken by the European Central Bank (ECB). At the same time you have tried to minimise the bill for German taxpayers by insisting that bailed-out states implement strict austerity programmes and, more generally, by resisting calls for debt mutualisation—code for Germany underwriting the euro area—while demanding greater central control over all national budgets.

II. Bluntly, the plan isn’t working. Greece is a disaster zone. Ireland and Portugal are making some progress (it was encouraging that Ireland was able to raise some money from the markets in July) but they still have a long way to go and could easily be knocked off course. Worse, Spain looks as if it may need a full bail-out rather than the partial one for its banks you had hoped would suffice. And Spanish sickness is infecting Italy, undermining all the good work that Mario Monti has been doing since the Italians saw sense and got rid of Silvio Berlusconi, as you had been urging behind the scenes. Meanwhile François Hollande isn’t doing enough to get France into shape and is playing the usual French game of calling for Germany to do more while resisting your attempts to centralise control at the European level. Mario Draghi, the ECB’s president, has calmed things down for the moment, but his plan could easily come unstuck.

III. The position is dangerously unstable. If capital flight from the peripheral economies gathers pace, it could trigger runs on entire banking systems. That would put the ECB—and thus, indirectly, the Bundesbank and Germany—on the hook for deposits worth trillions of euros. The domestic politics are already ugly in several countries, notably Greece. This is poisoning our position in southern Europe, where our help is increasingly seen as a new form of German tutelage. The situation is deteriorating in Germany, too, where your ability to act is being limited by a backlash against bail-outs and against the euro itself. If anything, the backlash in Finland and the Netherlands is even more vicious.

THE CASE FOR PLAN B

IV. Hence the need to consider an alternative strategy. The aim of this contingency plan is not the complete break-up of the 17-country euro area. That would be against the German national interest, destroying the hard-won respect we have achieved since the second world war by embracing European integration. And it would needlessly damage our economy by bringing back currency risk for trade with countries such as Austria and the Netherlands, which have adapted perfectly well to the euro. Plan B seeks to save the euro by surgery, excising states that cannot cope rather than clinging to the vain hope that they can regain their health within the euro zone.

V. We propose two options. First, the one that may be forced on you anyway: an exit by Greece arising from gross dereliction of its duties under the various bail-out agreements. We have taken as a given that MPs in the Bundestag will not sanction a single euro more in bail-out money to Athens. If that forces the Greeks out, so be it. Second, we also consider a wider exit of other countries that have failed the euro test. We think this should include all the states that have already been rescued, or are requesting bail-outs, because those countries share with Greece a fundamental loss of competitiveness and vulnerability to foreign capital flight. This means that they cannot be cured within a reasonable period of time while staying within the euro.

VI. In assessing the two options we have relied mainly on a cost-benefit analysis. That has been informed, where relevant, by historical precedents and the legal position (we are well aware of your concern that Germany must at all times be seen as law-abiding). We also look briefly at some of the practical issues involved in an exit. Naturally, we have taken into account the political constraints you face both at home and among your fellow European leaders. Caution is your watchword, so we’ve highlighted the risks of things going wrong if you adopt Plan B.

CAN AN EXIT HAPPEN IN THE FIRST PLACE?

VII. We start with the most basic question of all: can one or more countries leave (or be forced out of) the euro, both legally and practically? As a matter of legal principle, the answer is no, because when countries joined the euro the conversion of their former currencies was supposed to be “irrevocable”: a Hotel California that you can never leave. Indeed, a legal opinion published by the ECB in 2009 argued that because European treaties did not conceive of the possibility of a country leaving the euro, an exit would require them to leave the European Union (EU) as well. That would exacerbate the economic pain because the departing state would lose access to both the single market and valuable regional-support funds.

VIII. But we think this argument of legal impossibility is overstated. European laws are in constant flux because of the ease with which new agreements can supersede old ones. The Maastricht treaty of 1992 banned bail-outs, but you have yourself authorised two agreements allowing them: the temporary rescue fund and the permanent European Stability Mechanism, whose legality our constitutional court is considering at the moment. Similarly, we think that it will be possible to find a way round the supposedly binding rule that a country exiting the euro would also have to leave the EU.

IX. What about the practical obstacles to an exit? There are two main ones. First, it would take several months to design, print and distribute an entirely new currency, leaving a departing country bereft of new cash. Second, news of a country leaving or being ejected would almost certainly leak, prompting bank runs so massive that they would overwhelm even the ECB’s ability to counter them. That would lead to a total (and chaotic) break-up rather than a controlled one.

X. We think it will be possible to deal with both these practical difficulties. Yes, it took six months to launch a new currency when, for example, the Czech-Slovak monetary union broke up in 1993. And yes, they were able to overstamp existing notes as either Czech or Slovak—something that would not work for a country like Greece, which relies so heavily on euros spent by tourists. But modern economies have become much less reliant on cash than they used to be. We think a country could get by for a few months through enhanced use of electronic payments (which might also flush out more of the black economy) and by using existing euro notes and coins for small transactions, as proposed by Roger Bootle, the head of Capital Economics, a consultancy, who recently won a competition set by Lord Wolfson, a British businessman, on how one or more countries might leave the euro.

XI. The worry about bank runs is more justified, but we think it too can be overcome. The most obvious way would be to keep the exit decision completely secret until the weekend it was implemented. That is tricky, because you would need to convince other European leaders ahead of a council meeting, and news would be bound to leak. But if the news did get out, then a state leaving the euro could immediately impose an extended bank holiday and implement capital controls (normally illegal under European law, but there is a get-out clause for up to six months in exceptional circumstances). That should deal with the problem.

AN EXIT OF GREECE ALONE

XII. Assuming the legal and practical hurdles to an exit by any state can be surmounted, then the first option is for Greece to leave, which on the face of it looks less risky than a bigger break-up. One immediate difficulty is that the Greeks don’t want to go, so they would have to be expelled. There are two ways they could be forced out: first, by cutting off the flow of bail-out funds, which would mean that the Greek government would have to meet its deficits by issuing IOUs that would start to circulate as a de facto parallel currency, trading at a discount to euros; second, by cutting Greek banks off from refinancing from the ECB and its payments system. The first approach might take some time but would create such monetary chaos that a clean break would eventually seem preferable. The second would force the issue since the banks would collapse without access to ECB liquidity.

XIII.What would happen then? Even if Greece did slide towards the exit rather than jumping, at some stage the government would have to complete the process by introducing the new drachma one weekend when the markets were closed. All assets, debts and contracts written under domestic law, including bank deposits and loans, would be redenominated one-for-one from euros to drachmas. Crucially, the moment the markets reopened, the drachma would depreciate, probably by more than 50%.

XIV. That devaluation, if not squandered in a lurch towards hyperinflation, could deliver Greece from its current misery of perpetual recession by letting it regain lost competitiveness at a stroke, rather than by grinding down domestic costs over several years. That should swiftly deliver a hefty boost to the sagging economy from net trade. But what would it mean for Germany?

XV. First, you can count on the move being popular—and not just in Germany—making it feasible to win support from other European leaders whose electorates are just as fed up with the feckless Greeks. Second and vitally, expelling Greece would draw a line under the costs of bailing it out and prevent it from becoming a permanent drain on German taxpayers. Third and scarcely less important, the decision would give bite to conditionality, sending a stern lesson to the rest of Europe that bail-out terms cannot be flouted with impunity.

XVI. Set against these benefits there will be costs. From a strategic perspective, there is the danger of Greek politics souring still further and the country becoming a permanent trouble-spot in the eastern Mediterranean, even if it is out of the euro. To fend off that possibility it will be essential to show goodwill by keeping Greece in the EU. So it will in fact need a third bail-out (only we will call it an aid package) to pay for things like essential drugs for patients. We think this could be capped at, say, €50 billion ($60 billion) of which Germany would chip in a third, or around €17 billion.

XVII.That will be just the beginning. Drawing a line also means ending the fiction that our loans to Greece will be repaid in full. Germany, along with other European creditor nations, will face hefty losses (see chart 1) arising from our exposure to Greece. First, there is the money already disbursed: almost €130 billion. Second, the ECB still owns Greek government bonds worth some €40 billion. Third, the Bank of Greece owes the ECB about €100 billion in so-called Target2 debts, which have arisen through the Target2 payments system as local banks made up for the drain of deposits out of Greece by borrowing from the central bank. That adds up to an exposure of over €270 billion, or 3% of euro-wide GDP. (We don’t include the indirect exposure we all have through our stakes in the IMF, which has lent Greece about €20 billion, since the IMF usually gets its money back).

XVIII. Some of that €270 billion might be recovered, but it would be irresponsible to bank on any of it. The devaluation would increase—in drachma terms—Greece’s euro indebtedness. That will force the Greek government wherever possible to redenominate its liabilities into drachma, inflicting heavy losses on creditors; and it may follow that up with a further write-down. Prudence suggests that we should assume no recovery and that Germany will be on the hook for a third of European losses—more than its formal share of just over a quarter, on the assumption that the other bailed-out states won’t be able to pay anything at all. That would cost Germany €90 billion, raising the bill (including the aid package) to almost €110 billion. On top of this taxpayers might have to stump up €10 billion to support German banks as they wrote off their claims on Greece. Assuming that the state picked up half the resulting losses, this would take the total German bill to nearly €120 billion, or 4.5% of GDP.

GOING FOR BROKE

XIX. If that was that, it would be a bargain compared with the likely present value of transfers from Germany to Greece over the next few years and maybe decades. But there is a sizeable risk that a Grexit could turn into a calamity, as markets reacted badly to the admission that euro membership was no longer irreversible. At worst there could be a market collapse to rival the one that took place after the Lehman bankruptcy in late 2008, which could in turn trigger a recession on the scale of the desperate downturn of 2008-09. In the panic, you would come under intense pressure (Barack Obama would be on the line immediately) to concede debt mutualisation without getting the quid pro quo of fiscal control at a European level that you have been demanding. After holding out for so long against demands that you write a blank cheque, that is what you might well end up having to do.

XX. Given the risk that Germany might have to pay such a heavy price for a Greek exit, does that mean Plan B is a non-starter? Not necessarily. Another conclusion might be that the seemingly safer scenario of an exit by Greece alone is in fact the riskier option. If Germany is going to have to make big concessions to deal with the exit of one state, it might make more sense to make such concessions in conjunction with more radical surgery that really gets to grip with the euro crisis. Altogether, five out of the 17 member states have been rescued or asked for a bail-out—testimony to the fact that they have not been able to cope with the rigours of the single currency. The other four—first Ireland, then Portugal, and now Spain and Cyprus—are also teetering in the relegation zone. Expelling them too might be better for them, for the euro and for Germany, because it would make the remaining euro area more viable.

XXI. The plight of the other four economies reflects private debt (especially in Cyprus, Ireland and Spain) as much as public debt (which was clearly at fault in Greece and to a lesser extent in Portugal). But the fundamental weakness that they all now share with Greece is that they owe foreigners far more than they own abroad. In each of the five countries, external liabilities exceeded domestically owned foreign assets by between 80% and 100% of GDP in 2011, putting them in a league of their own within the euro area (see chart 2). Italy, by contrast, has low net external liabilities worth only 21% of GDP (lower than America’s 27%).

XXII. External-debt levels are far higher in the five countries than in emerging economies that have fallen victim to “sudden stops”, in which foreign investors and banks stop lending and try to pull out their money. Small wonder that the markets have lost confidence in them. But even though bail-out loans can shield governments, that loss of confidence continues to undermine the peripheral economies, as foreign deposits are withdrawn and foreign investors refuse to buy their debt. Central-bank funding is plugging the gap, but that makes banks worryingly beholden to the ECB, causing them to clamp down on their lending to firms and households. This squeezes the economy even more tightly and makes it harder to get the public finances in order.

XXIII. As well as being burdened by unsustainable levels of external debt, all five economies share the misery of trying to regain lost competitive ground through internal devaluation, in which domestic costs are ground down year after year. With the exception of Ireland, which has achieved a worthwhile reduction in its unit labour costs (though after the biggest rise of all), you could hardly select a group of countries less able to make a success of internal devaluation. Labour markets in southern Europe are notorious for protecting insiders (permanent workers) at the expense of outsiders (employees on temporary contracts or the unemployed). This rigidity means that firms cut their labour costs through hiring freezes and by sacking temporary employees, rather than by reducing pay rates.

XXIV. Some progress is being made, but as in a marathon, it is the second half of the race that is the most agonising. Unemployment has already risen to perilously high levels: around 15% of the workforce in Ireland and Portugal and 25% of the workforce in Spain. Ireland has been running a small current-account surplus and deficits have generally fallen (though they remain very high in Cyprus and Greece) but they would be far worse if the peripheral economies were not so depressed, which has slashed demand for imports.

XXV. What this suggests is that if Greece has to depart, it should not go alone. Like Greece, the other four bail-out countries would gain from the swift improvement in competitiveness that currency devaluations would achieve, provided credible policies were pursued to ensure it was not frittered away in runaway inflation. And if politics can trump the law for Greece, then the same should be true for all five countries, allowing them to stay in the EU and retain access to the single market.

XXVI. Such a move would of course come as a tremendous shock, and it would be essential to protect Italy and France at once by making far-reaching concessions that shift the remaining euro area towards mutualisation of debt and the creation of a banking union. But that would be less of a setback for Germany than before, because in principle there should be less need for burden-sharing in a more viable monetary union. Indeed, the most important potential benefit of this bigger break-up is that it could bring the euro crisis to a decisive end by restoring confidence in a smaller but sturdier single-currency area.

XXVII. In addition, a line would have been drawn under potentially much higher costs by preventing the bail-outs from becoming a permanent flow of transfers. This is what happened in Germany after reunification and is still happening. Recent research by the IMF shows that the flow of money to the poorer German states has created a form of benefit dependency. The German public’s big fear is the same outcome, writ large, across the euro area. For example, a transfer union across the existing single-currency zone based on the Canadian model would seek to make governments’ revenues more equal. Transferring cash so that the poorest governments (including Greece and Spain) had a level of revenue close to that of a mid-tier but still below-average country like Ireland could involve annual transfers of €250 billion—of which €80 billion would need to come from Germany, around 3% of its GDP.

XXVIII. In the short term, however, the cost of a five-country exit would clearly be much heavier than that of a Grexit. Although the other four departing states would be in a less desperate condition than Greece, they might also need some aid to smooth the way—a further €100 billion, say, of which Germany’s share would be €33 billion. The additional exposure through official loans would be bearable because the other four bail-outs were individually much smaller than Greece’s. Altogether euro-area governments have made commitments approaching €200 billion—the same as to Greece—but actual disbursements have been less than half that. The big exposure lies in the euro system. The ECB is estimated to hold an additional €80 billion of Irish, Portuguese and Spanish bonds bought over the past two years to calm markets. In addition, it has claims on the other four countries through the Target2 system of around €600 billion.

XXIX. That would bring the cost arising from an exit of all five countries to €1.15 trillion, of which Germany’s share would be €385 billion, or 15% of its GDP. The additional expense of bank bail-outs would increase this to €496 billion, or 19% of GDP, lifting German government debt from 81% of GDP in 2011 to 100% and imperilling Germany’s triple-A credit rating. German non-financial firms and individuals would also take a big hit on their claims of over €200 billion in the five economies.

XXX. The biggest risk associated with this scenario is that the moves towards debt mutualisation and a banking union might not, after all, be enough to stabilise the remaining euro area, resulting in a total break-up of the euro zone and triggering a savage recession with hugely damaging economic consequences. Markets invariably ask “who’s next?” and there is an obvious answer. Italy might not need to leave the euro on grounds of its net external liabilities, and its primary budget (ie, before interest payments) is under control. But its public-debt burden of 120% of GDP is the second-highest (after Greece’s) in the euro area. And it is mired in recession again. Like Greece, Italy has found it hard to live with the single currency. Growth has been dismal over the past decade (Mr Berlusconi was an economic calamity) and unit labour costs have risen sharply. The task of restoring Italian competitiveness would be far harder once the five departing economies had adopted new, much cheaper currencies.

XXXI. The more that markets fretted about Italy, the more they would also fret about France, given its strong trading and financial links with Italy. Given all this, it would be very difficult for Germany to get support in the European Council for this more drastic plan. The political obstacles to co-ordinating a solution that keeps the euro area intact may seem insuperable, but getting agreement for a planned ejection of five countries would be even more daunting.

CONCLUSION

XXXII. Of the two options, our judgment is that the larger break-up makes more overall economic sense than an exit of Greece alone. But we must emphasise that the economic and financial risks of it going wrong are much greater, and pushing it through would be an order of magnitude more difficult than co-ordinating an exit by Greece alone. Finally, a drawback associated with both options, even if they were to work, is that many of the benefits would lie in the future (by not having to make transfers to peripheral Europe) whereas the costs would be felt here and now—and blamed on you and your government.

A note attached to this memorandum by a member of her staff indicates that after reading it, Mrs Merkel thought long and hard about how to respond. She is a scientist by training, a politician by vocation and, most important of all, a cautious person by temperament. After much deliberation she concluded that despite the advantages of Plan B compared with her current strategy, she was unwilling to countenance the associated risks—at least for the moment. She ordered the memo to be shredded, resolving that if the euro area is to fragment, it will not be at her behest. But the staff member who was told to destroy the memo thought it might be useful to keep Plan B in reserve just in case. Plucking it from the shredder, he filed it away instead. No one need ever know that the German government had been willing to think the unthinkable. Unless, of course, the memo 

ANGELA MERKEL, the German chancellor—and also, in effect, the euro area’s boss—has always insisted that she wants to preserve the euro area in its current form. But as the euro crisis intensifies and the potential bills for Germany mount, she would be imprudent not to be considering a Plan B. Drafted in utmost secrecy by a few trusted officials for the chancellor’s eyes only, this is what the memorandum outlining a contingency plan might say.

TO: Angela Merkel
FROM: ???
SUBJECT: Plan B

Related topics

THE CURRENT IMPASSE

I. Since the euro crisis started over two years ago you have said that Germany will defend the single currency, based on your conviction, shared by business and the political class, that its survival is in our national interest. To that end Germany has pledged large amounts of public money, both in our contributions to various rescue funds and through the Bundesbank’s share of risks taken by the European Central Bank (ECB). At the same time you have tried to minimise the bill for German taxpayers by insisting that bailed-out states implement strict austerity programmes and, more generally, by resisting calls for debt mutualisation—code for Germany underwriting the euro area—while demanding greater central control over all national budgets.

II. Bluntly, the plan isn’t working. Greece is a disaster zone. Ireland and Portugal are making some progress (it was encouraging that Ireland was able to raise some money from the markets in July) but they still have a long way to go and could easily be knocked off course. Worse, Spain looks as if it may need a full bail-out rather than the partial one for its banks you had hoped would suffice. And Spanish sickness is infecting Italy, undermining all the good work that Mario Monti has been doing since the Italians saw sense and got rid of Silvio Berlusconi, as you had been urging behind the scenes. Meanwhile François Hollande isn’t doing enough to get France into shape and is playing the usual French game of calling for Germany to do more while resisting your attempts to centralise control at the European level. Mario Draghi, the ECB’s president, has calmed things down for the moment, but his plan could easily come unstuck.

III. The position is dangerously unstable. If capital flight from the peripheral economies gathers pace, it could trigger runs on entire banking systems. That would put the ECB—and thus, indirectly, the Bundesbank and Germany—on the hook for deposits worth trillions of euros. The domestic politics are already ugly in several countries, notably Greece. This is poisoning our position in southern Europe, where our help is increasingly seen as a new form of German tutelage. The situation is deteriorating in Germany, too, where your ability to act is being limited by a backlash against bail-outs and against the euro itself. If anything, the backlash in Finland and the Netherlands is even more vicious.

THE CASE FOR PLAN B

IV. Hence the need to consider an alternative strategy. The aim of this contingency plan is not the complete break-up of the 17-country euro area. That would be against the German national interest, destroying the hard-won respect we have achieved since the second world war by embracing European integration. And it would needlessly damage our economy by bringing back currency risk for trade with countries such as Austria and the Netherlands, which have adapted perfectly well to the euro. Plan B seeks to save the euro by surgery, excising states that cannot cope rather than clinging to the vain hope that they can regain their health within the euro zone.

V. We propose two options. First, the one that may be forced on you anyway: an exit by Greece arising from gross dereliction of its duties under the various bail-out agreements. We have taken as a given that MPs in the Bundestag will not sanction a single euro more in bail-out money to Athens. If that forces the Greeks out, so be it. Second, we also consider a wider exit of other countries that have failed the euro test. We think this should include all the states that have already been rescued, or are requesting bail-outs, because those countries share with Greece a fundamental loss of competitiveness and vulnerability to foreign capital flight. This means that they cannot be cured within a reasonable period of time while staying within the euro.

VI. In assessing the two options we have relied mainly on a cost-benefit analysis. That has been informed, where relevant, by historical precedents and the legal position (we are well aware of your concern that Germany must at all times be seen as law-abiding). We also look briefly at some of the practical issues involved in an exit. Naturally, we have taken into account the political constraints you face both at home and among your fellow European leaders. Caution is your watchword, so we’ve highlighted the risks of things going wrong if you adopt Plan B.

CAN AN EXIT HAPPEN IN THE FIRST PLACE?

VII. We start with the most basic question of all: can one or more countries leave (or be forced out of) the euro, both legally and practically? As a matter of legal principle, the answer is no, because when countries joined the euro the conversion of their former currencies was supposed to be “irrevocable”: a Hotel California that you can never leave. Indeed, a legal opinion published by the ECB in 2009 argued that because European treaties did not conceive of the possibility of a country leaving the euro, an exit would require them to leave the European Union (EU) as well. That would exacerbate the economic pain because the departing state would lose access to both the single market and valuable regional-support funds.

VIII. But we think this argument of legal impossibility is overstated. European laws are in constant flux because of the ease with which new agreements can supersede old ones. The Maastricht treaty of 1992 banned bail-outs, but you have yourself authorised two agreements allowing them: the temporary rescue fund and the permanent European Stability Mechanism, whose legality our constitutional court is considering at the moment. Similarly, we think that it will be possible to find a way round the supposedly binding rule that a country exiting the euro would also have to leave the EU.

IX. What about the practical obstacles to an exit? There are two main ones. First, it would take several months to design, print and distribute an entirely new currency, leaving a departing country bereft of new cash. Second, news of a country leaving or being ejected would almost certainly leak, prompting bank runs so massive that they would overwhelm even the ECB’s ability to counter them. That would lead to a total (and chaotic) break-up rather than a controlled one.

X. We think it will be possible to deal with both these practical difficulties. Yes, it took six months to launch a new currency when, for example, the Czech-Slovak monetary union broke up in 1993. And yes, they were able to overstamp existing notes as either Czech or Slovak—something that would not work for a country like Greece, which relies so heavily on euros spent by tourists. But modern economies have become much less reliant on cash than they used to be. We think a country could get by for a few months through enhanced use of electronic payments (which might also flush out more of the black economy) and by using existing euro notes and coins for small transactions, as proposed by Roger Bootle, the head of Capital Economics, a consultancy, who recently won a competition set by Lord Wolfson, a British businessman, on how one or more countries might leave the euro.

XI. The worry about bank runs is more justified, but we think it too can be overcome. The most obvious way would be to keep the exit decision completely secret until the weekend it was implemented. That is tricky, because you would need to convince other European leaders ahead of a council meeting, and news would be bound to leak. But if the news did get out, then a state leaving the euro could immediately impose an extended bank holiday and implement capital controls (normally illegal under European law, but there is a get-out clause for up to six months in exceptional circumstances). That should deal with the problem.

AN EXIT OF GREECE ALONE

XII. Assuming the legal and practical hurdles to an exit by any state can be surmounted, then the first option is for Greece to leave, which on the face of it looks less risky than a bigger break-up. One immediate difficulty is that the Greeks don’t want to go, so they would have to be expelled. There are two ways they could be forced out: first, by cutting off the flow of bail-out funds, which would mean that the Greek government would have to meet its deficits by issuing IOUs that would start to circulate as a de facto parallel currency, trading at a discount to euros; second, by cutting Greek banks off from refinancing from the ECB and its payments system. The first approach might take some time but would create such monetary chaos that a clean break would eventually seem preferable. The second would force the issue since the banks would collapse without access to ECB liquidity.

XIII.What would happen then? Even if Greece did slide towards the exit rather than jumping, at some stage the government would have to complete the process by introducing the new drachma one weekend when the markets were closed. All assets, debts and contracts written under domestic law, including bank deposits and loans, would be redenominated one-for-one from euros to drachmas. Crucially, the moment the markets reopened, the drachma would depreciate, probably by more than 50%.

XIV. That devaluation, if not squandered in a lurch towards hyperinflation, could deliver Greece from its current misery of perpetual recession by letting it regain lost competitiveness at a stroke, rather than by grinding down domestic costs over several years. That should swiftly deliver a hefty boost to the sagging economy from net trade. But what would it mean for Germany?

XV. First, you can count on the move being popular—and not just in Germany—making it feasible to win support from other European leaders whose electorates are just as fed up with the feckless Greeks. Second and vitally, expelling Greece would draw a line under the costs of bailing it out and prevent it from becoming a permanent drain on German taxpayers. Third and scarcely less important, the decision would give bite to conditionality, sending a stern lesson to the rest of Europe that bail-out terms cannot be flouted with impunity.

XVI. Set against these benefits there will be costs. From a strategic perspective, there is the danger of Greek politics souring still further and the country becoming a permanent trouble-spot in the eastern Mediterranean, even if it is out of the euro. To fend off that possibility it will be essential to show goodwill by keeping Greece in the EU. So it will in fact need a third bail-out (only we will call it an aid package) to pay for things like essential drugs for patients. We think this could be capped at, say, €50 billion ($60 billion) of which Germany would chip in a third, or around €17 billion.

XVII.That will be just the beginning. Drawing a line also means ending the fiction that our loans to Greece will be repaid in full. Germany, along with other European creditor nations, will face hefty losses (see chart 1) arising from our exposure to Greece. First, there is the money already disbursed: almost €130 billion. Second, the ECB still owns Greek government bonds worth some €40 billion. Third, the Bank of Greece owes the ECB about €100 billion in so-called Target2 debts, which have arisen through the Target2 payments system as local banks made up for the drain of deposits out of Greece by borrowing from the central bank. That adds up to an exposure of over €270 billion, or 3% of euro-wide GDP. (We don’t include the indirect exposure we all have through our stakes in the IMF, which has lent Greece about €20 billion, since the IMF usually gets its money back).

XVIII. Some of that €270 billion might be recovered, but it would be irresponsible to bank on any of it. The devaluation would increase—in drachma terms—Greece’s euro indebtedness. That will force the Greek government wherever possible to redenominate its liabilities into drachma, inflicting heavy losses on creditors; and it may follow that up with a further write-down. Prudence suggests that we should assume no recovery and that Germany will be on the hook for a third of European losses—more than its formal share of just over a quarter, on the assumption that the other bailed-out states won’t be able to pay anything at all. That would cost Germany €90 billion, raising the bill (including the aid package) to almost €110 billion. On top of this taxpayers might have to stump up €10 billion to support German banks as they wrote off their claims on Greece. Assuming that the state picked up half the resulting losses, this would take the total German bill to nearly €120 billion, or 4.5% of GDP.

GOING FOR BROKE

XIX. If that was that, it would be a bargain compared with the likely present value of transfers from Germany to Greece over the next few years and maybe decades. But there is a sizeable risk that a Grexit could turn into a calamity, as markets reacted badly to the admission that euro membership was no longer irreversible. At worst there could be a market collapse to rival the one that took place after the Lehman bankruptcy in late 2008, which could in turn trigger a recession on the scale of the desperate downturn of 2008-09. In the panic, you would come under intense pressure (Barack Obama would be on the line immediately) to concede debt mutualisation without getting the quid pro quo of fiscal control at a European level that you have been demanding. After holding out for so long against demands that you write a blank cheque, that is what you might well end up having to do.

XX. Given the risk that Germany might have to pay such a heavy price for a Greek exit, does that mean Plan B is a non-starter? Not necessarily. Another conclusion might be that the seemingly safer scenario of an exit by Greece alone is in fact the riskier option. If Germany is going to have to make big concessions to deal with the exit of one state, it might make more sense to make such concessions in conjunction with more radical surgery that really gets to grip with the euro crisis. Altogether, five out of the 17 member states have been rescued or asked for a bail-out—testimony to the fact that they have not been able to cope with the rigours of the single currency. The other four—first Ireland, then Portugal, and now Spain and Cyprus—are also teetering in the relegation zone. Expelling them too might be better for them, for the euro and for Germany, because it would make the remaining euro area more viable.

XXI. The plight of the other four economies reflects private debt (especially in Cyprus, Ireland and Spain) as much as public debt (which was clearly at fault in Greece and to a lesser extent in Portugal). But the fundamental weakness that they all now share with Greece is that they owe foreigners far more than they own abroad. In each of the five countries, external liabilities exceeded domestically owned foreign assets by between 80% and 100% of GDP in 2011, putting them in a league of their own within the euro area (see chart 2). Italy, by contrast, has low net external liabilities worth only 21% of GDP (lower than America’s 27%).

XXII. External-debt levels are far higher in the five countries than in emerging economies that have fallen victim to “sudden stops”, in which foreign investors and banks stop lending and try to pull out their money. Small wonder that the markets have lost confidence in them. But even though bail-out loans can shield governments, that loss of confidence continues to undermine the peripheral economies, as foreign deposits are withdrawn and foreign investors refuse to buy their debt. Central-bank funding is plugging the gap, but that makes banks worryingly beholden to the ECB, causing them to clamp down on their lending to firms and households. This squeezes the economy even more tightly and makes it harder to get the public finances in order.

XXIII. As well as being burdened by unsustainable levels of external debt, all five economies share the misery of trying to regain lost competitive ground through internal devaluation, in which domestic costs are ground down year after year. With the exception of Ireland, which has achieved a worthwhile reduction in its unit labour costs (though after the biggest rise of all), you could hardly select a group of countries less able to make a success of internal devaluation. Labour markets in southern Europe are notorious for protecting insiders (permanent workers) at the expense of outsiders (employees on temporary contracts or the unemployed). This rigidity means that firms cut their labour costs through hiring freezes and by sacking temporary employees, rather than by reducing pay rates.

XXIV. Some progress is being made, but as in a marathon, it is the second half of the race that is the most agonising. Unemployment has already risen to perilously high levels: around 15% of the workforce in Ireland and Portugal and 25% of the workforce in Spain. Ireland has been running a small current-account surplus and deficits have generally fallen (though they remain very high in Cyprus and Greece) but they would be far worse if the peripheral economies were not so depressed, which has slashed demand for imports.

XXV. What this suggests is that if Greece has to depart, it should not go alone. Like Greece, the other four bail-out countries would gain from the swift improvement in competitiveness that currency devaluations would achieve, provided credible policies were pursued to ensure it was not frittered away in runaway inflation. And if politics can trump the law for Greece, then the same should be true for all five countries, allowing them to stay in the EU and retain access to the single market.

XXVI. Such a move would of course come as a tremendous shock, and it would be essential to protect Italy and France at once by making far-reaching concessions that shift the remaining euro area towards mutualisation of debt and the creation of a banking union. But that would be less of a setback for Germany than before, because in principle there should be less need for burden-sharing in a more viable monetary union. Indeed, the most important potential benefit of this bigger break-up is that it could bring the euro crisis to a decisive end by restoring confidence in a smaller but sturdier single-currency area.

XXVII. In addition, a line would have been drawn under potentially much higher costs by preventing the bail-outs from becoming a permanent flow of transfers. This is what happened in Germany after reunification and is still happening. Recent research by the IMF shows that the flow of money to the poorer German states has created a form of benefit dependency. The German public’s big fear is the same outcome, writ large, across the euro area. For example, a transfer union across the existing single-currency zone based on the Canadian model would seek to make governments’ revenues more equal. Transferring cash so that the poorest governments (including Greece and Spain) had a level of revenue close to that of a mid-tier but still below-average country like Ireland could involve annual transfers of €250 billion—of which €80 billion would need to come from Germany, around 3% of its GDP.

XXVIII. In the short term, however, the cost of a five-country exit would clearly be much heavier than that of a Grexit. Although the other four departing states would be in a less desperate condition than Greece, they might also need some aid to smooth the way—a further €100 billion, say, of which Germany’s share would be €33 billion. The additional exposure through official loans would be bearable because the other four bail-outs were individually much smaller than Greece’s. Altogether euro-area governments have made commitments approaching €200 billion—the same as to Greece—but actual disbursements have been less than half that. The big exposure lies in the euro system. The ECB is estimated to hold an additional €80 billion of Irish, Portuguese and Spanish bonds bought over the past two years to calm markets. In addition, it has claims on the other four countries through the Target2 system of around €600 billion.

XXIX. That would bring the cost arising from an exit of all five countries to €1.15 trillion, of which Germany’s share would be €385 billion, or 15% of its GDP. The additional expense of bank bail-outs would increase this to €496 billion, or 19% of GDP, lifting German government debt from 81% of GDP in 2011 to 100% and imperilling Germany’s triple-A credit rating. German non-financial firms and individuals would also take a big hit on their claims of over €200 billion in the five economies.

XXX. The biggest risk associated with this scenario is that the moves towards debt mutualisation and a banking union might not, after all, be enough to stabilise the remaining euro area, resulting in a total break-up of the euro zone and triggering a savage recession with hugely damaging economic consequences. Markets invariably ask “who’s next?” and there is an obvious answer. Italy might not need to leave the euro on grounds of its net external liabilities, and its primary budget (ie, before interest payments) is under control. But its public-debt burden of 120% of GDP is the second-highest (after Greece’s) in the euro area. And it is mired in recession again. Like Greece, Italy has found it hard to live with the single currency. Growth has been dismal over the past decade (Mr Berlusconi was an economic calamity) and unit labour costs have risen sharply. The task of restoring Italian competitiveness would be far harder once the five departing economies had adopted new, much cheaper currencies.

XXXI. The more that markets fretted about Italy, the more they would also fret about France, given its strong trading and financial links with Italy. Given all this, it would be very difficult for Germany to get support in the European Council for this more drastic plan. The political obstacles to co-ordinating a solution that keeps the euro area intact may seem insuperable, but getting agreement for a planned ejection of five countries would be even more daunting.

CONCLUSION

XXXII. Of the two options, our judgment is that the larger break-up makes more overall economic sense than an exit of Greece alone. But we must emphasise that the economic and financial risks of it going wrong are much greater, and pushing it through would be an order of magnitude more difficult than co-ordinating an exit by Greece alone. Finally, a drawback associated with both options, even if they were to work, is that many of the benefits would lie in the future (by not having to make transfers to peripheral Europe) whereas the costs would be felt here and now—and blamed on you and your government.

A note attached to this memorandum by a member of her staff indicates that after reading it, Mrs Merkel thought long and hard about how to respond. She is a scientist by training, a politician by vocation and, most important of all, a cautious person by temperament. After much deliberation she concluded that despite the advantages of Plan B compared with her current strategy, she was unwilling to countenance the associated risks—at least for the moment. She ordered the memo to be shredded, resolving that if the euro area is to fragment, it will not be at her behest. But the staff member who was told to destroy the memo thought it might be useful to keep Plan B in reserve just in case. Plucking it from the shredder, he filed it away instead. No one need ever know that the German government had been willing to think the unthinkable. Unless, of course, the memo 

Comments

  1. Maquiavel says:

    Pois.
    Passou ao lado de muita gente que foi a Rússia que acabou de safar o Chipre de um “resgate à la Merdkel”, fazendo um grande empréstimo ao Estado cipriota, que näo vai ter de aplicar um pacote austeritário demente e destrutivo, como a Grécia ou Portugal ou Espanha (que é já a seguir).

    • a demographia não engana só esgana e lava mais branco ...é racista acho.. says:

      sim o chipre é a grécia…só tem menos gente e minas de cobre que dão mais 300 anos que as da faixa piritosa

      o cobre dá pra moedas de rublo…
      és um Merdquiavel e dos grandes….

      • ê cá sou mai grego que sócrates says:

        geopolítica ó thalassa é depois de um carregamento de armas iranianas ter endividado explosivamente os cipriotas

        haver beneméritos russos que perderam 50% das bases no mediterrâneo desinteressadamente porem um pé fora dos dardanelos…pois

        navios matriculados em chipre têm quantos milhões de tones de arqueação bruta?

        os britânicos travaram uma guerra de guerrilha contra os independentistas cipriotas porque?

        a)lhes apetecia

        b) eram thalassas imperialistas

        c) eram marados como o merdquiavel?

        d)PS:dê

  2. maria celeste ramos says:

    Pacote austeritário demente é o termo – sempre viveram e enriqueceram à custa dos “pequenos” (espanha a puta que a pariu porque é igual) e depois ora bem austeridade – os bons exemplos veem de cima – não há um rico que o seja só à sua custa – às vezes creio que a mafia nunca há-de acabar e apenas muda de roupagem – e depois elogiam os que se desgraçaram a eles e a todos com guerras e depois a guerra +e outra e os portugueses que são mentecaptos chamam-lhe o motor do desenvolvimento – pois – quem trabalha para eles e o que dão em troca ?’ deslocalizar ?’ quando fecharam extinguindo a marinha grande e as vidreiras foi o princípio do fim pela mão de portugueses do governo que são os lacaios dos ricos – nem servidores são – são tipos sem “espinha” – a fábrica Irmãos Stephen ?? investir aqui o quê ou explorar mão de obra e depois irem-se ?’e agora nem “investem” – fazem abortar e falir – Europa o “boi branco” que se enfiou no “mar” adentro e desapareceu ?’ motor do desenvolvimento ou do SAQUE ?? quem é a alemanha dos bárbaros que derrotou o império Romano ?’ os tais que não aderiram ao euro e são sepratistas Blair esse criminoso ?? eu vejo tudo ao contrário dos outros e dos “intelectuais” – o mundo não é a preto e branco – é apenas preto (sem ser de áfrica)

    • Nuno Castelo-Branco says:

      Celeste, isto não começou agora. É o fecho da política de desenvolvimento industrial iniciada nos anos 40-60. Logo após o 25 de Abril, cometeram-se terríveis erros que não valerá a pena voltar a mencionar. Quando hoje se fala dos “grupos económicos portugueses” – onde está a antiga industria pesada, por exemplo? – esquecem-se daquilo que se fez em 74-76. Não convém lembrar, mas é isso mesmo.

      • Maquiavel says:

        Qual “antiga industria pesada”? A que se estabeleceu e sobreviveu até 1974 com o apoio do Estado Novo? A que estava tecnicamente falida em 1974?

        É que em Portugal näo havia mais nenhuma! Infelizmente!

        • Nuno Castelo-Branco says:

          Sim, essa mesmo. O Estado Novo apoiou-a, é verdade. Mas parece-lhe ter sido boa ideia a des-industrialização ? O que dizer então daqueles países onde o Estado controlava a totalidade da economia? Está-se então mesmo a ver que afinal de contas, para uns casos o controlo serve, para outros, não…

          • a demographia não engana só esgana e lava mais branco ...é racista acho.. says:

            ó moço cê responde a tutti-fruti? isse dá sarna?

            a indústria química do salazaristão ainda anda por aí …
            desde estarreja à refinaria do gaijo das cortiças

            indústria pesada nã é só siderurgia e desconstrução navalis
            que por acaso remendou petroleiros até depois da guerra irão iraque…responder a parolos merdquiavélicos cheios de trampa na mioleira

            estupidifica né…até thalassas…

          • Maquiavel says:

            A des-industrialização em Portugal foi feita prioritariamente pelo Cavaco.

            Nos países onde o Estado controlava a totalidade da economia, depois da privatizaçäo, as indústrias obsoletas fecharam, como é normal… mas por acaso também fecharam algumas que näo sendo obsoletas eram concorrentes das ocidentais (destas apenas se safou a Carl Zeiss).

            Mas nem sei porque o NC-B foi buscar estúltimas. É sabido que a indústria pesada portuguesa estava tecnicamente falida em 1974, e só se aguentava devido aos salários miseráveis e ajudas do Estado, nomeadamente a Lei do Condicionamento Industrial, que evitava o aparecimento/entrada de concorrentes.

  3. a demographia não engana só esgana e lava mais branco ...é racista acho.. says:

    a grécia tal como a tunísia têm um sistema lixado à nascença
    muito dependente do exterior
    e do que as famílias que monopolizam os bens estatais deixam fora dos bancos suissos

    mas a grécia tem muito mais para privatizar a preço de saldo

    mas não é do seu interesse fazê-lo…

    a alemanha ou a nokia também não têm interesse em cobrir os déficits gregos que subsidiaram e incrementaram durante anos

    a indústria farmacêutica que ganhou biliões com os anti-depressivos e anti-ácidos que impingiu aos gregos tamém nã

  4. a demographia não engana só esgana e lava mais branco ...é racista acho.. says:

    geopolítica é os thalassas britânicos ajudados pelos amarikanos derrubarem mossadegh para terem pitroil baratucho durante 50 anos

    putogoal ou o berço da mariquice socrática

  5. ê cá sou mai grego que sócrates says:

    nã jogam na geo plítica aplítica
    2 casos? nem dão pra 0,05….
    bai ber o rio tinto a españa que fazes milhó…
    ma nã caces elephantes…

  6. ê cá sou mai grego que sócrates says:

    leva o merdquiavel contigo e vê se fazes o que um amigo do bush fez ao companheiro de caça dele…
    agente agradecia
    é que já bastam os aventares do costume a aventar merda
    mas a do merdquiavel tá sempre fresca pôrra…
    aquilo tem o cérebro ligado em di rectum

Discover more from Aventar

Subscribe now to keep reading and get access to the full archive.

Continue reading